Why 23¢ per person per day does the job
Our job is to put in place a climate policy capable of solving the problem, but our job is not to solve it. That will take 50 or 100 years. We cannot commit future generations; we can only put in place an agreement capable of carrying out the necessary changes.
- The revenues from carbon pricing, and not the price, are seen lever for change.
- Environmentalists focus on far of targets, when cost are unknown will be many times higher.
Proof by example. Consider a simple example of carbon pricing. If the price of carbon is $30/ton, would anyone pay $50/ton to save carbon? No, they would just pay the price of carbon instead.
That puts a limit on the cost of abatement — at most a $30 carbon price can cost us $30 for each ton saved. But that’s “at most.” Insulating houses can save more money in heating bills than it costs to insulate. That’s a negative net cost. The Environmental Protection Agency assumes that on average the cost of saving emission will be half way between zero and $30 the the carbon price is $30. That gives us the EPA formula for cost, which is the most important formula in global-energy economics.
Table 1 also assumes a Green Fund that charges countries $2/ton for emissions above the world-average per-capita rate, and that funds low-emission countries at the same rate for emissions below the world average. It also assumes carbon pricing cuts emissions almost as much as the Waxman-Markey bill says it will — a 20% reduction by 2020.